The first germ of the Wide-Ownership Workshop Industrial Ecology idea came from visiting a makerspace, Freeside Atlanta. It used to be located in a complex of giant old Quonset-style former cotton warehouses, surrounded by barbed wire in a rough neighborhood. The complex was always open, with a guard at the gate – I’m not really sure what for – they seemed to let anybody in. It was a “temporary autonomous zone”, a scene. The several parallel buildings, each several hundred feet long had been split into dozens of workshops and other spaces, including a couple of illegal nightclubs. On the Thursday night I visited, it was energetic outside and in.
Freeside had several thousand square feet of all kinds of tools and materials. You could work all night if you felt like it and most of the other places would be active, too – when I visited, one guy was getting the latest iteration of a part run off on another shop’s laser cutter, while he went across the alley for a beer at the club. He got a sweetheart deal, paying only slightly more than the cost of running the cutter – in exchange, he would run off whatever the laser-cutter guy needed on Freeside’s tools.
Why couldn’t this continue? I wondered, though cool scenes never seem to last. Why couldn’t it be scaled up so you could make anything?
Another germ of the idea came from ISS engineer Dani Eder’s “Seed Factory Project”, which started as an idea for building a moon base with the lowest possible launch cost by first shipping up a self-reproducing mining and manufacturing base. Only things that couldn’t be produced from local materials would be shipped up: semiconductors, plastics, chemicals – but everything heavy in the facilities, vehicles, robots and other machinery would be made out of lunar aluminum, glass and so forth. Dani realized that this would be somewhat less impossible if you didn’t try to ship the self-reproducing factory to the moon first. After that the idea morphed into a non-automated sort of super-makerspace, which I wasn’t too enthusiastic about. Then his wikibook on the idea turned into a sort of giant government requirements document-style thing, which lost me totally.
I had long been enthusiastic about the idea of molecular nanotechnology, reading Drexler’s Engines of Creation in 1989, and his very technical Nanosystems when it came out. In 2005 I coached a couple of boys, age 10 and 11, from my electronics class for gifted homeschoolers in a project for the Toshiba Exploravision invention contest. One of the boys wanted to invent something that would let him be a for-real giant. I couldn’t think of a way immediately, but then I remembered “utility fog”, which should allow basically anything you could do in a Star Trek holodeck. We came up with a pretty detailed design, with processing, networking, cooling, power, optical phased-array collective displays, actuators … and how to apply it to education: telepresence, historical simulations and simulations of dangerous chemical experiments. Whittled it down to ten pages, somehow. It was the only entry in the state to get honors that year.
In 2014, I had an epiphany about how to make self-reproducing factories work economically with any degree of automation – not only to work economically, but to work better than the current economy. As I wrote then:
Each business has an incentive to pay as little as possible in wages, which today is becoming more and more possible through automation, but when everybody does this, demand dries up because fewer people have enough money to buy. The challenge is to not only make things people want, but also to have an economic environment in which they are paid enough to buy to buy the things made.
The most direct possible solution is to have the productivity of machines be directly owned by those who would otherwise be factory workers or passive investors.
Have the machines located together in a factory in a district of factories, but have each machine owned by a single person, each person owning enough machines to pay the equivalent of a middle- to upper-middle- class income from the machines’ productivity. Owners buy these machines with low-interest rate loans secured by the machines themselves. Owners swap time on their machines with owners of other machines, giving each owner access to many specialized tools, effectively multiplying their capital.
Owners can make not only products, but machines, particularly more specialized and productive machines. These both serve as security for new loans, but also produce money directly, since nominal “machine-hours” are the internal currency of the factory for swapping time on each others’ machines. Loans are also valued in machine-hours, as are the fees to insure, house and operate them.
[continued later]